Intervening in laissez-faire liberalism: Chicago’s shift on patents

Document Type

Article

Date of Original Version

1-1-2011

Abstract

The Chicago School is typically associated with a pro-patent position: they have defended patents on the grounds that they are vital to encourage innovation and have condemned claims that patents allow patent-holding i rms to extend their monopoly power from one market to another. the Nobel Prize–winning Chicago economist, George Stigler, claimed that an inventor’s i nancial incentive was optimum only if he had exclusive and perpetual ownership of the patent. Steven Cheung, a third-generation representative of the Chicago School, observed in 1977: “In a free society an individual owns his brain, and by way of a number of dif erent arrangements he may utilize and market the outputs of this mental resource to generate income” (Cheung 1977, 597). To Cheung, the patent system was the best way to facilitate this generation of income. In 1973, Ward Bowman, a principal proponent of the Chicago law and economics movement in the 1960s and 1970s, maintained that alleged forms of patent misuse might “actually be the most ei cient use of the patent from the social as well as the private point of view. It pays monopolists as well as competitors to be ei cient” (1973, 9). More recently, in 2006, Richard Epstein, a public face of Chicago law and economics, defended the pharmaceutical industry from prospective regulations. Taking a pro-patent position, he stated, “[Pharmaceutical companies] are very heavily dependent on the patent law, [which] have allowed these i rms to bring a wide variety of vital products to market” (Epstein 2006). However, members of the Chicago School did not always take a propatent position. In the 1930s, the respected University of Chicago professor and self-identii ed classical liberal, Henry Simons, described monopoly in all its forms, including “gigantic corporations” and “other agencies of price control,” as “the great enemy of democracy” because they undermined the necessary condition for democracy to l ourish, namely, a competitive market. In championing democracy and competitive markets, Simons displayed a broad hostility toward patents and claimed that the patent system enabled the creation and extension of monopoly power.

Publication Title, e.g., Journal

Cambridge University Press

Volume

9781107013414

Share

COinS